Markus Brunnermeier

The safe asset potential of EU-issued bonds

Retrieved on: 
Saturday, January 21, 2023

The lack of euro-denominated safe assets and the fragmentation of the market are problematic.

Key Points: 
  • The lack of euro-denominated safe assets and the fragmentation of the market are problematic.
  • In the absence of a supranational euro-denominated safe asset, a flight to safety would entail capital flowing out of vulnerable countries and into safe havens.
  • Both initiatives were proposed in the context of the EU’s response to the recession in the wake of the coronavirus (COVID-19) pandemic.
  • As of December 2021, the amount of outstanding EU bonds had grown to €215 billion in total.
  • The first SURE bonds were issued in October 2020, while the first NGEU bonds were issued in June 2021.
  • By 2028 NGEU volumes are foreseen to reach €800 billion, more than twelve times the level in December 2021.
  • Including the approved funding for other smaller programmes, the total available amount of EU bonds is set to exceed €1 trillion by 2028.
  • This stability of EU yield spreads does not mean that EU bonds will automatically become a supranational euro-denominated safe asset.
  • A safe asset is traded in liquid markets.
  • Market liquidity ensures that investors can sell their asset at any time without causing a major change in the market price.
  • (2022) we also argue that a safe asset’s market liquidity should be sufficiently high to accommodate central banks’ monetary policy operations.
  • Finally, the perception of EU bonds as safe assets also hinges on the continuation of their favourable regulatory treatment.
  • For such an instrument to be viable, a deep and liquid repo market would need to evolve first.

Side effects of monetary easing in a low interest rate environment: reversal and risk-taking

Retrieved on: 
Friday, November 11, 2022

Since 2014, the European Central Bank (ECB) and other central banks have been pursuing a negative interest rate policy (NIRP).

Key Points: 
  • Since 2014, the European Central Bank (ECB) and other central banks have been pursuing a negative interest rate policy (NIRP).
  • The controversy about monetary policy in a low rate environment hinges on the existence of a zero-lower bound (ZLB) on interest rates (Coibion et al., 2012).
  • In a low or negative interest rate environment, it becomes harder for banks to pass on the reduction in the policy rate to their depositors.
  • This means a policy rate cut translates into a lower interest rate margin and reduces the net worth of banks.
  • In our recent paper (Heider and Leonello, 2021), we present a simple conceptual framework to show how a policy rate cut affects both bank lending and risk-taking in a low or negative interest rate environment versus a high interest rate environment.
  • The substitutability between loans, deposits and bonds is the channel through which the policy rate affects loan and deposit rates.
  • Reversal occurs when a cut in the monetary policy rate reduces lending instead of increasing it (Brunnermeier and Koby, 2018).
  • The level of the policy rate at which lending is maximal identifies the reversal rate.
  • Reversal is related to but not directly triggered by reduced profits from a contraction in the net interest margin at the ZLB.
  • This implies that when the policy rate falls below the reversal rate, a policy rate cut leads to increased risk-taking.
  • With market power, an increase in the lending volume reduces the loan rate, which then further reduces the benefit from screening.
  • Our research suggests that there are potential side effects of monetary stimulus in a low interest rate environment: reduced lending and increased risk-taking by banks.

Low rates and bank stability: the risk of a tipping point

Retrieved on: 
Friday, November 11, 2022

This has spurred academic and policy discussions about the economic implications of such low rates for the banking sector.

Key Points: 
  • This has spurred academic and policy discussions about the economic implications of such low rates for the banking sector.
  • It develops a model closely based on Allen and Gale (1998) and shows the existence of a critical policy rate level, dubbed the tipping point.
  • Past the tipping point, an interest rate cut has a negative net effect on bank capital and may indeed result in bank insolvency.
  • From the model, we learn which bank characteristics matter for the tipping point and how they affect it.
  • Using these theoretical results, we can use data on banks to quantify the tipping point.
  • To discuss bank solvency, we need to understand what constitutes the assets of a bank from an economic point of view.
  • A banks deposit franchise, which is generally not capitalised on bank balance sheets, is also a relevant bank asset.
  • With this concept of solvency in mind, the question becomes: what is the effect of a low policy rate on bank assets?
  • Past the tipping point, the deposit-franchise effect dominates and a policy rate cut hurts bank solvency.
  • Our observed value for average bank asset maturity (4.5 years) implies that a 0.55% policy rate is the tipping point.
  • [4]
    More work is required to obtain a sound quantification of the tipping point, also for the euro area.

Benefits of macroprudential policy in low interest rate environments

Retrieved on: 
Friday, November 11, 2022

Short-term interest rates in the euro area and the United States

Key Points: 
  • Short-term interest rates in the euro area and the United States

    Notes: Benchmark short-term nominal interest rate (panel A) and natural rate of return (panel B) for the euro area and the United States.

  • Low levels of the natural rate for protracted periods of time pose challenges for the conduct of conventional monetary policy.
  • This can happen because the ELB on nominal interest rates precludes the policy rate from tracking the natural rate if the latter falls below the bound.
  • In economies with low natural rates, such as the euro area today, macroprudential policy can have benefits for the effectiveness of conventional monetary policy, in addition to safeguarding financial stability.
  • The natural rate which is a risk-free, short-term real interest rate therefore increases as well.
  • The above benefit points to a novel complementarity between macroprudential policy and conventional monetary policy, which takes place only in environments with low interest rates.
  • If these conditions hold, macroprudential policy boosts the natural rate above the ELB, and it does so unintentionally, simply as a by-product of safeguarding financial stability.
  • That is, macroprudential policy still improves the effectiveness of conventional monetary policy, but it does not allow the policy rate to accommodate aggregate demand appropriately without hitting the ELB.
  • In economies with low natural rates, macroprudential policy can have benefits for the effectiveness of conventional monetary policy, in addition to safeguarding financial stability.
  • These benefits arise because macroprudential policy boosts the natural rate simply as a by-product of containing systemic risk in financial markets which gives the central bank more room for stimulating aggregate demand, especially during downturns.